Saturday, 25 June 2016

Baumol's Contested Market Model


Baumol's Contested Market Model


1.       INTRODUCTION:
The literature on contestable markets emerged from a research program that claimed two principal achievements in advancing economic knowledge, and two important policy contributions. The theory of contestable markets was advanced as a generalization of the theory of perfectly competitive markets, and a generalization that (in contrast with the previous literature) endogenizes the determination of industry structure.
This theory was first developed by the American economist W.J.Baumol in the early 1980s. The theory argues that what really matters in determining an industry's price and output is not, in reality, whether the industry is perfectly competitive or a monopoly, but the potential of new firms to enter or leave the market. The theory is based on the idea that a firm may enjoy a monopoly position within a market, but if there existed the real threat of competition from other firms, this would force the firm to behave as if it actually faced competition; that is, the firm would not pursue a policy of charging exorbitant prices to make excessive profits.
2.     THE THEORY:
 A.         What is a contestable market ?
The term 'contestability' has nothing to do with the number of firms currently in the industry, but refers instead to the ease with which firms are able to enter or leave a market; a perfectly contestable market is one in which there are no barriers or costs to entry or exit: the greater these are, the less contestable is the market, and thus the greater is the monopoly power of existing firms; so for a market to be contestable, a barrier to entry, such as a patent protecting technical knowledge, must be absent.
 B.           Important conditions for contestable markets to prevail are:
             The first condition is that the new firms can enter the market with the same cost conditions as the existing firm or firms. If the existing firm enjoys some cost advantage as compared to the potential entrants in the market, then the new firms that enter the market cannot succeed in competing with the existing one which can afford to lower the price and inflict losses on the new entrants.
             The second condition for the contestable markets is that firms should be able to leave or exit the market (i.e. industry) without incurring any capital loss. If the production in an industry involves much capital investment which is specific to that industry and therefore of no use elsewhere, leaving the industry will entail losses equal to the sunk costs. Sunk costs act as an important barrier to the entry of new firms and are therefore deterrent to the existence of contestable markets.
             The third condition for contestable markets to exist is that the potential entrants must be at no disadvantage as compared to the existing firms with regard to the production technology or product quality as perceived by the consumers. Any lack of access to the same production technology as used by the existing firms prevents the new entrants from competing the existing firms on the basis of cost or product quality. This would work to reduce the threat by potential entrants and enable the existing firms to charge higher than competitive price and earn supernormal profits.
            The last condition for the contestable markets to exist is that the new entrants must be able to engage in ‘hit and run’ tactics. That is, entry should be free and costless so that the new entrants enter the market or industry and make profits and exit the industry before the existing firms adjust their prices downward.

C.    Evaluation:
     The theory of contestable markets is often seen as an alternative to the traditional, Neo-classical, theory of the firm. Perfectly contestable markets can deliver the theoretical benefits of perfect competition, but without the need for a large number of firms. However a perfectly contestable market is not possible in real life. Instead, we talk about the degree of contestability of a market. The more contestable a market the closer it will be to a perfectly contestable market.
This theory argue that determining price and output is not actually dependent on the type of market structure, in other words whether it is a monopoly or perfectly competitive market, but rather the threat of competition. Hence, for example a monopoly protected by high barriers to entry (e.g. it owns all the strategic resources) will make supernormal or abnormal profits with no fear of competition. However, in this same case if it did not own the strategic resources for production then other firms could easily enter the market, leading to higher competition and thus lower prices, thus making the market more contestable.
Price setting in a contestable market is illustrated in the following figure .Suppose there are two firms in an industry, that is, there is duopoly in the product market. DD is the demand curve for the industry’s product. The average and marginal cost curves of each firm are shown.

The threat of entry of new firms leads each duopolist to charge a price OP (which is equal to their minimum average cost) and produces output equal to Oq. The total output OQ will be equal to two times Oq. (That is OQ = 2Oq). Each firm earns zero economic profits.
Though the two firms can enter into tacit collusion and push up the price and earn supernormal profits, they do not do so because they think new entrants will enter industry quickly and undercut price and in this way inflict losses on them. To prevent entry of new firms and avoid competition with them each duopolist produces OQ output and charges OP price.
By producing at the lowest minimum average cost they are able to enjoy all the economies of scale. Thus, in producing the level of output at the minimum average cost and charging a price equal to it, the two firms behave like a perfectly competitive firm.

3.  Implications of the theory:
The theory implies that, given easy entry to and exit from an industry, monopoly or oligopoly firms will behave as if they actually existed in perfect competition; that is they will:
    1.  Equate MC with MR to maximise profits
    2.Only earn normal profits (AR = ATC) in the long run, because if supernormal profits were made, new firms would enter the industry increasing supply and driving down price to a level where only normal profits are made; and if losses are made, some firms will be forced to leave the industry, causing supply to fall and price to rise back to a level consistent with the making of normal profits.
    3.Operate with productive efficiency on the lowest point of the ATC curve where AC = MC; if this were not the case, new firms could enter the industry, produce at the most efficient level, price their goods more competitively and force existing firms out.
   4. Operate with allocative efficiency where P = MC; this will occur because the earning of long run normal profits requires that AR or price should equal AC, and as AC = MC (see above point), the MC should equal the price.
4.   Criticisms of the theory:
The theory of contestable markets has been criticized, among others by Shepherd who points out that it is based on extremely unrealistic assumptions regarding entry and exit of new firms. According to him, in the real world entry is not free and exit is not costless. The extent to which the theory of contestable markets may be applied in practice is limited. Two pre-requisites may not be met:
 Firstly, firms' sunk costs must be low so that they can easily leave the market. However, in reality sunk costs may be extremely high, even when capital is transferable.
    Secondly, the specific technical knowledge necessary to operate in the industry must be freely available. However, sole possession of technical knowledge, often protected by patent, is a common and powerful barrier to entry to monopolistic markets where production is of a highly sophisticated nature, and is underpinned by extensive R&D - for example, the case of the drugs industry.
5.  RELEVANCE OF THE THEORY IN REALITY:
The applicability of the theory to real-world situations may be questioned, however, particularly as there are very few markets which are completely free of sunk costs and entry and exit barriers. Low-cost airlines remain a commonly referenced example of a contestable market; entrants have the possibility of leasing aircraft and should be able to respond to high profits by quickly entering and exiting. However, it is now generally admitted that Baumol's judgment that the US airline industry was therefore best left deregulated was incorrect, since the now duly deregulated industry is "well on its way" to evolving into a concentrated oligopoly. More generally, experimental evidence collected since the publication of Baumol's paper has suggested that perfectly competitive markets would – if they existed – behave in the way Baumol outlined, the performance of imperfectly contestable markets (i.e. real-world markets) depends "on actual rather than potential competition", perhaps in part due to the range of "strategic responses" available to incumbents that were not considered by Baumol as part of his theory.

The theory of contestable markets has been used to argue for weaker application of antitrust laws, as simply observing a monopoly market may not prove that a firm is exploiting its market power to control the price level. Baumol himself argued based on the theory for both deregulation in certain industries and for more regulation in others
6.   CONCLUSION
To conclude, the threat of new entrants can lead to the existing monopolists and oligopolists to behave like a competitive firm in some situations but when there exist substantial sunk investment costs, the existing firms have an edge over the new entrants and charge higher than competitive price and make large supernormal profits. We thus see that contestable market theory does not apply to all monopolistic and oligopolistic market situations.



              7.REFERENCES:
                (i) Jhingan M.L, Advanced Economic Theory,13th revised and enlarged edition
                     Published:vrinda publication(p) limited,Delhi.

1 comment: