Sunday 20 November 2016

Non- tariff Barriers of International Trade



Introduction:
Trade across political boundaries is interrupted by a bucket of barriers which do not let the countries to exploit their comparative advantages. Whenever a good crosses the international lines a set of duties known to as tariff coupled with some non-tariff restrictions emerge to limit the spirit of international trade.

What is ‘Non-Tariff-Barriers
Non-Tariff Barriers are obstacle to international trade which are not an import or export duty. They may take the form of import licensing, rules for valuation of goods at customs, pre-shipment inspections, subsidies, customs delays, technical barriers, trade prepared investment measures import quotas or other systems preventing trade.

Discussion
Non-tariff barriers can be discussed by classifying them in the following headings
1.       Protectionist policies
2.       Assistance policies
3.       Non-protectionist policies

Protectionist Policies
Restricting import is a way to protect domestic firms. Protectionist policy helps domestic firms at the expense of other countries. Example of this form of barrier includes Import quotas; local content requirements; public procurement practices etc. Quota limits the trade in physical terms, imposed on import and export of certain goods for a certain period of time. 

Assistance Policies
The instruments included in this category are meant for the help of domestic firms and enterprises irrelevant to the expense of other countries. Examples are -Domestic subsidies, antidumping laws etc. Because of subsidy production cost in a nation falls significantly and prices go down which outcompetes the existing exporters.

Non-protectionist policies
This type of trade-barrier is for the protection of the health and safety of people and the environment. Licensing, packaging, and labeling requirements, sanitary and phytosanitary (SPS) rules, food, plant and animal inspections, import bans based on objectionable fishing or harvesting methods are some of the prominent examples of this type of barrier. The most common instrument is the licensing. It requires that the authority issues permits for foreign trade transactions of import and export commodities included in the lists of licensed merchandises.


Monday 18 July 2016

Rationalisation of Indian Tax System

What is Rationalization of Taxation?
Rationalization of taxation is an attempt made by the fiscal authority to change the pre-existing  ad-hoc pattern of taxation into one which is based on a set of published rules after simultaneous research and practical observation. The aim and purpose of rationalization of tax system is to bring about efficiency, coordination and control of the tax collecting procedure

Rationalization of taxation in India
An introduction: After independence the Govt. of India initiated its Five Years planning in 1951 with an aim to pace the way of economic development in the country. The acceleration of economic development required a huge amount of revenue to meet capital and revenue expenditure as well as bulk development and maintenance imports. Therefore rationalization in the tax system became a need of hour for the economy.
Indian economy was gone through a structural change in 1991 and the government was forced to adopt a set of fiscal reforms. Aim was to reduce the fiscal deficit and inflation. To meet this twin objective it was necessary to increase the tax revenue. On the other hand it was carefully observed by the policymakers that increase in tax rate may lead to the deterioration of willingness to work of the citizens and the strategy may lead to the move for black money. Therefore the rationale behind such policy prescription may appear to be highly questionable. Rationalization was brought through widening of tax base and modernizing of tax administration.

Strategies of Rationalizing of Tax System
One of the reasonable steps was taken by the govt. in 1991 by setting up the Tax Reforms Committee under the Chairmanship of Raja J. Chelliah to examine the then tax structure of the country and suggest appro­priate reforms therein. The committee submit­ted its report in January 1993, it made several recommendations including the simplification of tax system, steps to discourage tax evasion and much more. As recommended by the committee many changes were brought into the Indian tax system. Important among them are:
1.      To make the direct tax system more ef­fective, it was necessary to reduce the tax rate so that there would be less tax evasion and avoidance. There was also the need to narrow down the spread between the lowest rate and maximum mar­ginal rate. To neu­tralize the fall in revenue due to lowering of the rates of taxation some of the tax incentives were withdrawn and the tax base was broadened.
2.      The personal income tax system has been restructured by lowering rates, introducing few slabs, providing a higher exemption limit and by reducing saving-linked tax exemption. Initial exemption limit for the levy of income tax has been raised from Rs. 22,000 in 1991 to Rs. 1,00,000 in 2007-08. The number of slabs has been reduced from 4 to 3 (i.e., 10 p.c., 20 p.c. and 30 p.c.). In 2016-17 budget the exemption limit has been raised to Rs 4 Lakh from earlier 2.5 Lakh of 2015-15.
3.      Presumptive tax (lump-sum) for small traders, retailers and small road transport op­erators has been introduced. To widen the tax net, in the 1994-95 budget, a service tax at the rate of 5 p.c. on the amount of telephone bills, premium payments for non-life insurance and on commission/brokerage charged by the stock-brokers was introduced. At least 100 types of services are subject to service tax as against 3 in 1994-95. In 2015 Union budget also service tax was proposed to increase.
4.      Since 1994-95, a number of provisions were introduced to widen the tax base. These in­clude taxation for small business, estimated income scheme for persons engaged in the business of civil construction, plying, leasing or hiring of trucks; tax deduction at source introduced on interest on term deposits in­come in respect of units of mutual funds, pro­fessional fees and host of contracts.
5.      Corporate tax rates have been reduced and simplified over the past few years. At present, the rate of corporate tax for domestic compa­nies is 30 p.c. and for foreign companies 40 p.c. of their net profit. With a view to tack­ling the phenomenon of zero tax companies having substantial book profits, a ‘minimum alternate tax’ (MAT) was introduced in the 1996-97 budget.
6.      To promote research and development ac­tivities—five-year tax holiday for investments in infrastructure facilities, power generation and distribution in backward states and electronics hardware and software parks.
7.      Government has also taken several meas­ures since 1991-92 to reform the indirect tax structure by reducing the number of rates, re­moving exemptions, and by switching over to ad valorem rates. Import duties which rose to more than 150 p.c. in several cases prior to reform have been reduced in a phased man­ner to 10 p.c. by 2007-08.
8.      The ex-Finance Minister of India, Pranab Mukherjee in his Budget speech indicated the government's intent of merging all taxes like Service Tax, Excise and VAT into a common Goods and Service Tax by the year 2011. To achieve this objective, the rate of Central Excise and Service Tax were targeted to be progressively altered and brought to a common rate. However, as of May 2015, Goods and Services Tax Bill had not been passed by the Parliament because of disruption by Opposition Allies (INC) on some State level issues.  Now, Service Tax and Excise will be inclusive part of GST in due course of time.
9.      Budget 2016 focused on tax rationalization and simplification while unveiling steps to boost 'Make in India'. In direct tax, the govt. is losing about Rs 1lakh crore because of exemptions. The shortfall in direct taxes to the tune of Rs 40,000 crore is targeted to make up by robust collections in indirect taxes and the total tax collection target for the fiscal will be met for the first time in five years. The income tax department is trying to widen its base, as currently 3.5% of total population pays the income tax.

Consequences of Rationalization
As a consequence of tax reform measures, tax rev­enues increased to 18.3 p.c. of GDP in 2007- 08. Overall tax reforms since July 1991 have helped in correcting the imbalance in the struc­ture of revenue sources. The share of direct taxes in GDP rose from 2.1 p.c. in 1990-92 to 5.7 p.c. in 2007-08. Also, the share of direct taxes in gross tax revenue rose from 19 p.c. in 1990-91 to 30.2 p.c. in 1995-96 and to 48.8 p.c. in 2007-08. Improved performance of the services and manufacturing- sector has helped to keep tax revenues buoyant. Further, higher growth in rev­enues relative to the growth in revenue ex­penditure resulted in a decline in revenue deficit to 1.9 p.c. of GDP in 2006-07 as against 4.4. p.c. in 2002-03. Same is true about fiscal deficit that declined to 3.4 p.c. in 2006-07 from 5.9 p.c. in 2002-03. These macroeconomic changes have allowed India to be more appropriate to become a quick decision maker (in Capital Account Convertibility etc.) and an emerging super power.

Saturday 25 June 2016

Baumol's Contested Market Model


Baumol's Contested Market Model


1.       INTRODUCTION:
The literature on contestable markets emerged from a research program that claimed two principal achievements in advancing economic knowledge, and two important policy contributions. The theory of contestable markets was advanced as a generalization of the theory of perfectly competitive markets, and a generalization that (in contrast with the previous literature) endogenizes the determination of industry structure.
This theory was first developed by the American economist W.J.Baumol in the early 1980s. The theory argues that what really matters in determining an industry's price and output is not, in reality, whether the industry is perfectly competitive or a monopoly, but the potential of new firms to enter or leave the market. The theory is based on the idea that a firm may enjoy a monopoly position within a market, but if there existed the real threat of competition from other firms, this would force the firm to behave as if it actually faced competition; that is, the firm would not pursue a policy of charging exorbitant prices to make excessive profits.
2.     THE THEORY:
 A.         What is a contestable market ?
The term 'contestability' has nothing to do with the number of firms currently in the industry, but refers instead to the ease with which firms are able to enter or leave a market; a perfectly contestable market is one in which there are no barriers or costs to entry or exit: the greater these are, the less contestable is the market, and thus the greater is the monopoly power of existing firms; so for a market to be contestable, a barrier to entry, such as a patent protecting technical knowledge, must be absent.
 B.           Important conditions for contestable markets to prevail are:
             The first condition is that the new firms can enter the market with the same cost conditions as the existing firm or firms. If the existing firm enjoys some cost advantage as compared to the potential entrants in the market, then the new firms that enter the market cannot succeed in competing with the existing one which can afford to lower the price and inflict losses on the new entrants.
             The second condition for the contestable markets is that firms should be able to leave or exit the market (i.e. industry) without incurring any capital loss. If the production in an industry involves much capital investment which is specific to that industry and therefore of no use elsewhere, leaving the industry will entail losses equal to the sunk costs. Sunk costs act as an important barrier to the entry of new firms and are therefore deterrent to the existence of contestable markets.
             The third condition for contestable markets to exist is that the potential entrants must be at no disadvantage as compared to the existing firms with regard to the production technology or product quality as perceived by the consumers. Any lack of access to the same production technology as used by the existing firms prevents the new entrants from competing the existing firms on the basis of cost or product quality. This would work to reduce the threat by potential entrants and enable the existing firms to charge higher than competitive price and earn supernormal profits.
            The last condition for the contestable markets to exist is that the new entrants must be able to engage in ‘hit and run’ tactics. That is, entry should be free and costless so that the new entrants enter the market or industry and make profits and exit the industry before the existing firms adjust their prices downward.

C.    Evaluation:
     The theory of contestable markets is often seen as an alternative to the traditional, Neo-classical, theory of the firm. Perfectly contestable markets can deliver the theoretical benefits of perfect competition, but without the need for a large number of firms. However a perfectly contestable market is not possible in real life. Instead, we talk about the degree of contestability of a market. The more contestable a market the closer it will be to a perfectly contestable market.
This theory argue that determining price and output is not actually dependent on the type of market structure, in other words whether it is a monopoly or perfectly competitive market, but rather the threat of competition. Hence, for example a monopoly protected by high barriers to entry (e.g. it owns all the strategic resources) will make supernormal or abnormal profits with no fear of competition. However, in this same case if it did not own the strategic resources for production then other firms could easily enter the market, leading to higher competition and thus lower prices, thus making the market more contestable.
Price setting in a contestable market is illustrated in the following figure .Suppose there are two firms in an industry, that is, there is duopoly in the product market. DD is the demand curve for the industry’s product. The average and marginal cost curves of each firm are shown.

The threat of entry of new firms leads each duopolist to charge a price OP (which is equal to their minimum average cost) and produces output equal to Oq. The total output OQ will be equal to two times Oq. (That is OQ = 2Oq). Each firm earns zero economic profits.
Though the two firms can enter into tacit collusion and push up the price and earn supernormal profits, they do not do so because they think new entrants will enter industry quickly and undercut price and in this way inflict losses on them. To prevent entry of new firms and avoid competition with them each duopolist produces OQ output and charges OP price.
By producing at the lowest minimum average cost they are able to enjoy all the economies of scale. Thus, in producing the level of output at the minimum average cost and charging a price equal to it, the two firms behave like a perfectly competitive firm.

3.  Implications of the theory:
The theory implies that, given easy entry to and exit from an industry, monopoly or oligopoly firms will behave as if they actually existed in perfect competition; that is they will:
    1.  Equate MC with MR to maximise profits
    2.Only earn normal profits (AR = ATC) in the long run, because if supernormal profits were made, new firms would enter the industry increasing supply and driving down price to a level where only normal profits are made; and if losses are made, some firms will be forced to leave the industry, causing supply to fall and price to rise back to a level consistent with the making of normal profits.
    3.Operate with productive efficiency on the lowest point of the ATC curve where AC = MC; if this were not the case, new firms could enter the industry, produce at the most efficient level, price their goods more competitively and force existing firms out.
   4. Operate with allocative efficiency where P = MC; this will occur because the earning of long run normal profits requires that AR or price should equal AC, and as AC = MC (see above point), the MC should equal the price.
4.   Criticisms of the theory:
The theory of contestable markets has been criticized, among others by Shepherd who points out that it is based on extremely unrealistic assumptions regarding entry and exit of new firms. According to him, in the real world entry is not free and exit is not costless. The extent to which the theory of contestable markets may be applied in practice is limited. Two pre-requisites may not be met:
 Firstly, firms' sunk costs must be low so that they can easily leave the market. However, in reality sunk costs may be extremely high, even when capital is transferable.
    Secondly, the specific technical knowledge necessary to operate in the industry must be freely available. However, sole possession of technical knowledge, often protected by patent, is a common and powerful barrier to entry to monopolistic markets where production is of a highly sophisticated nature, and is underpinned by extensive R&D - for example, the case of the drugs industry.
5.  RELEVANCE OF THE THEORY IN REALITY:
The applicability of the theory to real-world situations may be questioned, however, particularly as there are very few markets which are completely free of sunk costs and entry and exit barriers. Low-cost airlines remain a commonly referenced example of a contestable market; entrants have the possibility of leasing aircraft and should be able to respond to high profits by quickly entering and exiting. However, it is now generally admitted that Baumol's judgment that the US airline industry was therefore best left deregulated was incorrect, since the now duly deregulated industry is "well on its way" to evolving into a concentrated oligopoly. More generally, experimental evidence collected since the publication of Baumol's paper has suggested that perfectly competitive markets would – if they existed – behave in the way Baumol outlined, the performance of imperfectly contestable markets (i.e. real-world markets) depends "on actual rather than potential competition", perhaps in part due to the range of "strategic responses" available to incumbents that were not considered by Baumol as part of his theory.

The theory of contestable markets has been used to argue for weaker application of antitrust laws, as simply observing a monopoly market may not prove that a firm is exploiting its market power to control the price level. Baumol himself argued based on the theory for both deregulation in certain industries and for more regulation in others
6.   CONCLUSION
To conclude, the threat of new entrants can lead to the existing monopolists and oligopolists to behave like a competitive firm in some situations but when there exist substantial sunk investment costs, the existing firms have an edge over the new entrants and charge higher than competitive price and make large supernormal profits. We thus see that contestable market theory does not apply to all monopolistic and oligopolistic market situations.



              7.REFERENCES:
                (i) Jhingan M.L, Advanced Economic Theory,13th revised and enlarged edition
                     Published:vrinda publication(p) limited,Delhi.